Byrne's Dictionary of Irish Local History (37 page)

lunula
. A crescent-shaped early Bronze Age ornament worn by women around the neck.

lynchet
. A terrace of soil found on the downward side of a field, a consequence of soil creep from contour ploughing during medieval or earlier times.

M

mace
. A club, usually of iron with a wooden handle, designed to smash defensive armour.

machicolation
. An opening in the floor of a projecting parapet or in the roof of an entrance through which missiles, stones or hot liquids might be cast upon attackers. A murder-hole.

madder
. A climbing plant (
rubia tinctorum
), the root of which was used to make a medium to strong red dye.

maghery
. (Ir.,
machaire
, a plain) The area controlled by the English administration during the fifteenth century comprising the
Pale
and its
marches
(borders). The 1488 Act of Marches and Maghery defined the Pale boundaries as stretching from Dundalk to Dalkey and as far inland as 20 miles. By a series of parliamentary subsidies the maghery was enclosed piecemeal by ditches and castles as a defence against Irish raids. In 1495 Poynings' parliament obliged the march inhabitants to construct a double rampart and ditch on the boundary of the march with the maghery and additional ditches between the marches and the Irish. For defensive rather than administrative purposes the term ‘maghery', the land of peace, was sometimes applied to the Pale to distinguish it from the marches, the land of war. (Ellis,
Reform
, pp. 50–52.)

magistrate
. Dissatisfaction with the competence of many justices of the peace led to the emergence in Ireland of the magistrate. Lay part-time magistrates exercised the same judicial powers as a
justice of the peace
at the
quarter-sessions
but like the justices they proved unsuitable despite efforts by successive governments to improve their effectiveness. In 1795 (33 Geo. III c. 36) whole-time stipendiary magistrates exercising control over the city police force were appointed in Dublin. Stipendiary magistrates were introduced to be independent of local (especially Orange and Protestant) influence and control. This initiative proved so successful that from 1814 the lord lieutenant was empowered to appoint ‘magistrates of police' and an attendant constabulary force to pacify proclaimed areas. After 1822 resident stipendiary magistrates with no connection to the police could be appointed at the request of the justices of the county. Finally, the 1836 act (6 & 7 Will. IV, c. 13) which legislated for a national constabulary force also provided for the appointment of resident magistrates throughout the country. These, too, were independent of the police and reported to the
chief secretary
on the state of their districts. By 1912 there were 64 resident magistrates operating outside Dublin. The magistrate presided over
presentment
sessions of the
grand jury
at the
assizes
, acted as an
ex-officio
member of the
board of guardians
of a
poor law union
and in the mid-nineteenth century could appoint police sub-constables.
See
police.

mail
. Iron links woven into a metal shirt which was worn to protect the wearer from slashing blows during combat. It was less effective against piercings.

mainprise
. The action of procuring the release of a person – who would otherwise be committed to jail – by going surety for his appearance in court on a specific date.

mainpernor
. 1: The surety for a released prisoner's appearance in court on a specific date 2: A person who goes surety.

majority, age of
. Until 1985 (Age of Majority Act, s.2) the age of majority was 21 years. Prior to the introduction of the
Tenures Abolition Act
in 1662 the wardship and marriage of an heir in minority to the estate of a chief tenant (see
capite, in
) reverted to the crown for the duration of the minority. Customarily wardships were auctioned to the highest bidder who was thereby enabled to take the profits of the estate and demand a marriage price. The guardian was required to maintain the ward and, after the Reformation, ensure that Catholic minors were educated as Protestants at Trinity College. Upon attaining his majority the heir must sue out livery in the
court of wards and liveries
and pay
relief
(a payment usually equivalent to one year's profits of the land) to obtain legal possession of his estate. The crown's pecuniary interest in the business of wardship was increased after the Reformation with the creation of a large number of chief tenancies on lands formerly held by the monasteries and it was the desire to maximise crown revenue from this source that led to the establishment of the court of wards and liveries. The
inquisition
post-mortem
was the process by which the state detected instances of heirs in minority.
See
ousterlemain.

Malthus, Thomas
(1766–1834). The economic and demographic theories of the English economist Thomas Malthus heavily influenced British government thinking on the question of poverty. This is manifest in the ideology which underpinned the 1834 Poor Law Act in England and its Irish equivalent when introduced four years later. Malthus maintained that population expands to the limit of subsistence and only grows when the means of subsistence permit. Population, however, grows exponentially while the food supply increases arithmetically. Thus the food supply will act as a check on population growth unless it is previously checked by self-restraint, vice or starvation, afflictions which can only be avoided by war or disease. Malthusian demographic theory was gloomy and pessimistic. Poverty was an inevitable feature of human existence and state or private charity, by removing the restraint of subsistence, encouraged the poor to procreate prolifically. Such thinking provided a powerful rationale for blaming the poor for their own misfortunes and absolved the state and the affluent of responsibility. Poor law should be abolished, Malthus maintained, because it limited the mobility of labour and encouraged fecundity. Money spent on relief was wasted. He thought workhouses should be established for severe distress but that conditions within them should be hard. Ireland, with its rapidly growing population, poverty and heavy dependence on a single root crop, appeared to present the English administration with the Malthusian economic model
par excellence
. In fact, however, population growth had begun to decelerate from 1841 and when the Great Famine struck Ireland was producing a surplus of food for export. Malthusian theory also overlooked the safety valve of emigration as a means of reducing demographic pressure on the food supply. The philosophy of Malthus is manifest in the minimalist stance of government during the famine including the stringent administration of poor relief within the workhouses, the ending of
outdoor relief
, an emphasis on local responsibility for distress, the reluctance of government to respond when the crisis became extreme and general during the late 1840s (and, indeed, to reduce what was available as the famine progressed), non-intervention in the markets to halt food leaving the country and agreements with merchants not to sell food below local market prices. (Kinealy,
This great calamity
, pp. 10–18; Ó Gráda,
Malthus
.)

maltster
. A maker of malt. In malt-making grain was softened by immersion in water and allowed to germinate after which it was used in the brewing and distilling of alcohol.

manchet
. The finest white wheaten bread.
See
paindemaine.

mandamus
, order of
. (L., we order) A command issuing from the
king's bench
directed to any individual or corporate body or inferior court requiring the performance of some specified duty which pertained to that individual or office.

maniple
. An embroidered strip of cloth worn over the left arm at the wrist by a priest at the eucharist.

manor
. An estate granted manorial status by crown charter, consisting not merely of land but also certain entitlements, such as the right to hold manorial courts (
court leet, court baron
and
court of piepowder
). It was therefore as much a social and legal as a geographical or economic construct. John Norden's 1607 definition of the manor as a ‘little commonwealth, whereof the tenants are the members, the land the bulk and the lord the head' neatly encapsulates the three interrelated elements without which a manor could not exist: a lord, tenants and land. In medieval Ireland five classes of tenants have been identified, not all of whom were present on every manor and some – by acquiring additional land under certain conditions – embraced two or more tenures. The highest status belonged to the freeholders, freemen whose estates were heritable and who could dispose of their land as they saw fit. Apart from owing suit of court the freeholders were free of labour services. The
firmarii
, leaseholders owing money rent and labour services, were also freemen as were the
gavellors
(
gavillari
) – rent-paying tenants-at-will who owed services and paid money rent. The
cottiers
(
cotagii
) paid rent for their cottages and
crofts
and worked for the lord and other tenants. At the lowest level were the betaghs (
betagii
), usually the most numerous group on the manor, who occupied the lowest social status and were equivalent to the unfree
bondsmen
and
villeins
of England. Although usually associated with medieval and early modern times, manorial courts persisted in Ireland into the mid-nineteenth century. See bailiff, hayward, infangenetheof, outfangtheof, pinder, seneschal. (
Report from the select committee of manor courts, Ireland,
HC 1837 (494) XV. 69; Gillespie, ‘A manor court', pp. 81–87.)

manor borough
. A small town absorbed into an adjacent or surrounding
manor
and entitled by royal charter to elect two members to the Irish parliament. There were six in Ireland, the medieval boroughs of Athboy and Ratoath and the four seventeenth-century creations of Mallow (James I), Doneraile, Granard and Mullingar (all Charles II). The lord of the manor exercised complete control over a tiny electorate of Protestant freeholders that ranged in size from 12 in Mullingar to 50 in Granard. Manor boroughs were freely bought and sold throughout the eighteenth century. Only Mallow survived the
Act of Union
.

manor courts
. In the eighteenth and nineteenth centuries the manor courts provided a small debt recovery service, exercised common law jurisdiction up to the sum of £200 and retained the ancient jurisdiction of court baron which was held as often as there was business to conduct. Legislation enacted in 1785 and again in 1787 aimed to regulate the courts and their records and ensure that presiding seneschals were suitably qualified. By 1837 there were about 200 manor courts operating in Ireland providing quick and relatively cheap redress to litigants. Critics attacked the seneschals for their incompetence and alleged that some manor courts were conducted in public houses. They were abolished in 1856 (22 Vict., c. 14). For the medieval and early modern manorial courts see
court leet, court baron
. (
Report from the select committee of manor courts, Ireland,
HC 1837 (494) XV. 69.)

mansard
. A roof with a double slope on either side, the lower slope having a steeper incline than the upper.

manse
. Dwelling of a
Presbyterian
or Anglican minister

Mansion House Committee
. A nineteenth-century charitable body of concerned citizens which relieved distress during the food shortages of 1831 and which was reconstituted in October 1845 in response to widespread unease generated by the spread of potato blight. Supported by the lord mayor and lord lieutenant, the committee pressed the government to provide relief works, halt the export of corn and shut down distilleries. In 1880, a new body, the Mansion House Fund for Relief of Distress in Ireland was established to provide financial support to local relief committees following the collapse of the potato crop that year. The lord mayor, Edmund Dwyer Grey, presided. By December 1880 the resulting relief fund had attracted subscriptions totalling in excess of £180,000. The minutes of this body were printed and an extensive collection of original records are held in the Dublin Civic Archives in Pearse Street.

mantle
. A
falling
or cloak

Manuscript sources for the history of Irish civilisation
. Edited by R. J. Hayes, director of the National Library of Ireland,
Manuscript sources for the history of Irish civilisation
is the most comprehensive guide to manuscript sources for Irish history and one of the first ports of call for historians engaged in serious research. It is the most thorough guide to manuscripts held in the National Library and lists most of the collections in public as well as in private hands, both in Ireland and abroad. Microfilm numbers appended to individual entries indicate that the relevant document is available on microfilm. A criticism that Hayes' work mainly drew on the printed catalogues of foreign libraries and overlooked the relevant National Archives has been partly addressed in the supplementary volumes.
See Periodical sources for the history of Irish civilisation
. (Hayes,
The manuscript sources
;
First supplement, 1965–75
.)

marcate
. Of land, as much as is worth one mark per year (13
s
. 4
d
.).

marches
. Frontier land of disputed ownership dividing one ethnic group from another.

mark
. Money of account, worth 13
s
. 4
d
. or two-thirds of a pound.

market cross
. A cross associated with market towns where public announcements were cried.

marksman
. An illiterate voter who exercised his franchise by placing his mark on the ballot paper.

Other books

Best Friends...Forever? by Krysten Lindsay Hager
Hawke's Tor by Thompson, E. V.
Tapped (Totaled Book 2) by Grice, Stacey
The Heat's On by Himes, Chester
Secret Language by Monica Wood
How to Please a Lady by Jane Goodger
River Angel by A. Manette Ansay
Descent Into Darkness by H. A. Kotys
All Around Atlantis by Deborah Eisenberg