The Price of Everything (30 page)

Read The Price of Everything Online

Authors: Eduardo Porter

But with a flock of about 1.15 billion, the modern Catholic Church has avoided radical strategies to build fervor by toughening up the rules. Perhaps it feared it could lose too many believers. Instead, it has sought to navigate narrow straits between tight strictures, which could turn off marginal believers sitting on the fence between the Church and the secular world, and openness, which would weaken the appeal of the Church for the more committed. By the standards of any secular corporation, the strategy has been wildly successful: Catholicism remains the largest religious institution in the world. Still, its efforts to soften the rules to accommodate modernity have cost it many true believers—who have decamped to the more strict and fervent denominations of evangelical Christianity.
In the 1960s, the Catholic Church struggled to adapt to a world that seemed intent on deviating from the straight and narrow. Wedded to a rigid biblical literalism, the Church seemed increasingly out of touch in this period of enormous social ferment. On April 8, 1966,
Time
magazine even splashed on its cover the question “Is God Dead?” in bloodred letters against a black background—and achieved its biggest newsstand sales in twenty years. “Secularization, science, urbanization—all have made it comparatively easy for the modern man to ask where God is and hard for the man of faith to give a convincing answer, even to himself,” wrote John T. Elson, the magazine’s religion editor.
The Church responded with a fateful decision to modernize. During the Second Vatican Council, which ended in 1965, the Church proclaimed religious freedom, embraced people of other Christian faiths, and even acknowledged truth in other religions. To make it easier on members in the pews, it relaxed the rules governing mass, encouraging use of vernacular languages rather than Latin so the faithful could understand what was going on. It even allowed incorporating elements from local customs into the liturgy.
For conservative Catholics the changes amounted to betrayal. Not only did the erosion of believers continue. It may have intensified. After peaking at 74 percent in 1958, by the end of the Council in 1965 weekly mass attendance among American Catholics had declined to 67 percent. Over the next four decades it plummeted to 45 percent. “Religions are in the unusual situation in which it pays to make gratuitously costly demands,” economist of religion Larry Iannaccone once told me. “When they weaken the demands they make on members, they undermine their credibility.” The Church has suffered similarly across the world. In Italy, its stronghold, only 27 percent of Italians say religion is very important to them. In Spain, the share of Catholics who go to mass every week declined from 44 percent in 1980 to 19 percent today.
It is unclear whether there is anything the Church can do to stop the bloodletting, as modernity puts pressure on religious dogma across the board. The current pope, Benedict XVI, has been working to undo some of the Second Vatican Council’s reforms. He reintroduced the Latin mass. And he brought back the plenary indulgence, an innovation introduced during the First Crusade in the eleventh century that consisted in a blanket pardon for repentant sinners to skip purgatory in exchange for good works and acts of contrition.
While the Second Vatican Council was all about adapting the teachings and rituals of the Church to a changing world, Pope Benedict focused on reimposing the primacy of the Church over reality. In an interview with the
New York Times,
the Reverend Tom Reese, a former editor of the Catholic magazine
America,
said: “The church wants the idea of personal sin back in the equation.” It felt the need to raise its prices to drive more loyal customers in.
WHAT THE CHURCH WANTS
There’s nothing in the most basic tenets of faith that necessitates an institutional church. But churches abound—recording its dogmas, classifying its rituals, and managing its taboos.
To those who share it, the fundamental appeal of faith derives from the community it creates. If that were religion’s only purpose, churches might not be so ubiquitous. But civilization gave faith another purpose: legitimization of power. For this, churches are indispensable. From pharaonic Egypt to medieval Europe and from Meiji Japan to contemporary Iran, rulers have derived their authority from the divine. Churches harness the beliefs in a spiritual world in the service of earthly power. They set themselves up as the ultimate arbiters of behavior, fitting rewards to virtue and punishments to crime.
During the high Middle Ages the Catholic Church offered a binary option: salvation or hell. To obtain forgiveness sinners had to submit to extremely difficult trials. But around the eleventh and twelfth century, at the peak of its power in Europe, the Church started relaxing its rules and broadening its offerings. It introduced the concept of purgatory, a halfway house where repentant sinners had to spend time after death before being allowed into heaven. It divided sins into the mortal and the venial, so it could introduce more fine-grained pricing of forgiveness and absolution. A key reform was allowing confession in secret before a priest, rather than in public before the whole town. And it began selling indulgences for money. These innovations reduced the average price of sin. Secret confessions allowed priests to use price discrimination—evaluating the wealth of individual sinners and adjusting monetary punishments according to sinners’ ability to pay. It did wonders for the Church’s finances.
 
 
THE CATHOLIC CHURCH
ultimately paid a price for these tweaks, as it battled to keep control over the market of medieval faith. It got greedy—collecting levies associated with a widening array of rules to fund a lavish existence. In 1501, during the reign of Henry VII, a papal bull established a price list of indulgences whereby the English could purchase absolution of all sins. Landed lay individuals with income exceeding £2,000 a year had to pay £3 plus 6 sovereigns and 8 dinars. At the other end of the income scale, people making between £20 and £40 a year only had to pay 16 dinars. People could pay to have the souls of relatives extricated from purgatory. Bishops regularly had to pay for their office. And royalty paid to get married.
The Church frowned on intermarriage within families as far back as the fourth century. The policy stemmed, in part, from concerns over interbreeding within families, which posed risks of having children with genetic malformations. But it had other objectives: nobles favored marriage between relatives because it worked to maintain property within the family. The Church feared this would lead to powerful dynasties that could rival its power. Moreover, a ban on intermarriage allowed it to charge rich families for “dispensations” from the rule.
The bans got progressively tighter. In the fourth century the Church banned marriage between first cousins. In the sixth century it extended the prohibition to fifth cousins and in the ninth century to sixth cousins. The bans were lucrative. In the eleventh century, the Duke of Normandy, who would come to be known as William the Conqueror, had to build two churches in Caen—the Abbaye aux Hommes and the Abbaye aux Dames—so Pope Leo IX would undo his excommunication after William married a distant cousin, Mathilda of Flanders, against the will of the Church.
 
 
THE CHURCH’S MANAGEMENT
of the behavioral price list might have sowed the seeds of its demise. There are several competing explanations of the Protestant Reformation that swept Europe in the sixteenth century. Martin Luther, the priest who led the attack, accused the Church of becoming corrupt and morally weak. Historians have argued that the Church allied itself with the losing side in the many wars that raged in Northern Europe. But to me the most compelling hypothesis is that believers were no longer getting value for money. The prices charged by the Church—which by the logic of faith are designed to tighten the bonds among the faithful—had lost their purpose.
The Church stopped working to inspire the faithful and focused instead on collecting rents. By adding sophisticated new ways to raise money from its followers, the Church became too expensive for believers and provided too little of its core services in return. This encouraged the entry of a rival into the market: Protestant Christianity, which came to offer believers direct access to God at a better price. It eliminated the rents and recovered the traditional link between costly sacrifice and religious rewards that had characterized faith since its earliest times.
This approach proved particularly fitting for the emergent capitalist economies that were beginning to develop in Northern European cities, where wealth was inherently less stable than among the landed feudal aristocracy. The Church never established the same alliances with entrepreneurs that it had developed with European nobility. Rather, entrepreneurs resisted its rent seeking and opposed its meddling in economic enterprise. So they chose the competing product.
SIN VS. THE SECULAR WORLD
Belief in a divine origin of the world has suffered a battering over the past few centuries. In the West, science has gradually replaced God in the schema of the physical world since Nicolaus Copernicus proved the earth was not at the center of everything in the sixteenth century, raising the question of why an omnipresent, omniscient God of everything would care so much about events on a little planet in some corner of the universe.
Since then the Big Bang proposed an alternative to God for the origin of the universe and Darwin’s theory of natural selection proposed an alternative explanation to the Bible’s for the origin of man. Neuroscience cut the soul out of the picture by equating mind and brain, and modern psychology even challenged religion as a path to happiness.
European sociologists from the eighteenth century onward, from Karl Marx to Émile Durkheim and Max Weber, argued that secular progress killed faith off. It undermined religion’s main precepts by providing believers with an alternative explanation of the world that didn’t rely on angels. And the edifice of costly rules and sacrifices that defined religious communities, providing them with a collective purpose that helped them succeed over the course of human evolution, was taken over by a secular framework of law. Democratic procedure has replaced religion’s menu of norms and taboos, encouraging solidarity through other means.
Secular states gradually took over the provision of education, medical care, and other elements of social insurance like pensions and support for the unemployed. As people became richer, more educated, more socially tolerant, and more politically free, religion lost its purpose. Belief in God declined during the second half of the twentieth century in virtually every Western European country, Japan, and even India. The percentage of Irish who go to church at least once a week fell from 82 percent in 1981 to 65 percent two decades later. In the Netherlands it fell from 26 percent to 14 percent.
 
 
STILL, THERE IS A
gaping hole in the secularization trend in the industrial world: the United States. Americans remain hooked on God despite spectacular economic progress over the past hundred years. In 2001, 46 percent of Americans attended religious services at least once a week, three percentage points more than two decades earlier. And more than three quarters of Americans reported believing in life after death, 12 percent more than did so in 1947. Religious enthusiasm in the United States is closer to that in less developed countries. Fifty-nine percent of Americans said religion was very important in their lives, according to a poll by the Pew Global Attitudes Project in 2002. This was at least twice the share of other developed nations but comparable to rates in Turkey, Mexico, and Venezuela.
The pattern has led a group of American economists and sociologists to posit that the secularization thesis is wrong. If faith declined in other rich countries, it was not due to less demand for religious services but to shoddy supply. Support for religion waned in Western Europe because the Catholic Church was a state-supported monopoly that grew lazy and allowed believers to drift away. Its services became too cheap to matter. By contrast, religion in the United States thrived because of a vibrant diversity that flowered when independence led to the strict separation of church and state. Dozens of churches sprang up to serve the disenchanted market of mainstream Christianity offering high prices and high cohesion. About one in eight American Protestants pray several times a week, compared to about one in thirty Catholics, according to surveys. Protestants are more likely than Catholics to believe in hell and they are more likely to belong to church-related social groups. Twenty-nine percent of Protestants say they try to proselytize strangers at least once a month. Only 11 percent of Catholics do that.

Other books

Missy's Gentle Giant by P D Miller
Irresistible Magic by Deanna Chase
What Washes Up by Dawn Lee McKenna
A Quiet Vendetta by R.J. Ellory
The Perfumer's Secret by Fiona McIntosh
Pleasure's Offering by Moira Sutton
This Shattered World by Amie Kaufman
The Pacific Conspiracy by Franklin W. Dixon