Authors: Professor Michael Hardt,Antonio Negri
Tags: #Philosophy, #Political, #Political Science, #General, #American Government
furnish us with the key we need. The passage from the formal
subsumption to the real must be explained through the practices
ofactive subjective forces. In other words, disciplinarity pushed to
its extreme, imposed by the global Taylorization oflabor processes,
cannot actually determine the need for a new form of command
256
P A S S A G E S O F P R O D U C T I O N
except through the expression ofactive social subjectivities. The
globalization of markets, far from being simply the horrible fruit
ofcapitalist entrepreneurship, was actually the result ofthe desires
and demands ofTaylorist, Fordist, and disciplined labor power across
the world. In this sense, the processes ofthe formal subsumption
anticipated and carried through to maturity the real subsumption,
not because the latter was the product ofthe former (as Marx himself
seemed to believe), but because in the former were constructed
conditions ofliberation and struggle that only the latter could con-
trol. The movements ofdesiring subjectivities forced the develop-
ment to go forward—and proclaimed that there was no turning
back. In response to these movements in both the dominant and
the subordinated countries, a new form of control had to be posed
in order to establish command over what was no longer controllable
in disciplinary terms.
P RIMITIVE A CCUMULATIONS
Just when the proletariat seems to be disappearing from the world stage,
the proletariat is becoming the universal figure of labor. This claim is not
actually as paradoxical as it may seem. What has disappeared is the
hegemonic position of the industrial working class, which has not disappeared
or even declined in numbers—it has merely lost its hegemonic position and
shifted geographically. We understand the concept ‘‘proletariat,’’ however,
to refer not just to the industrial working class but to all those who are
subordinated to, exploited by, and produce under the rule of capital. From
this perspective, then, as capital ever more globalizes its relations of production, all forms of labor tend to be proletarianized. In each society and across
the entire world the proletariat is the ever more general figure of social labor.
Marx described the processes of proletarianization in terms of
primitive accumulation,
the prior or previous accumulation necessary before capitalist
production and reproduction can begin to take place. What is necessary is
not merely an accumulation of wealth or property, but a
social
accumulation,
the creation of capitalists and proletarians. The essential historical process,
then, involves first of all divorcing the producer from the means of production.
For Marx it was sufficient to describe the English example of this social
D I S C I P L I N A R Y G O V E R N A B I L I T Y
257
transformation, since England represented the ‘‘highest point’’ of capitalist
development at the time. In England, Marx explains, proletarianization
was accomplished first by the enclosures of the common lands and the clearing
of peasants from the estates, and then by the brutal punishment of vagabond-age and vagrancy. The English peasant was thus ‘‘freed’’ from all previous
means of subsistence, herded toward the new manufacturing towns, and
made ready for the wage relation and the discipline of capitalist production.
The central motor for the creation of capitalists, by contrast, came from
outside England, from commerce—or really from conquest, the slave trade,
and the colonial system. ‘‘The treasures captured outside Europe by undisguised looting, enslavement and murder,’’ Marx writes, ‘‘flowed back to
the mother-country and were turned into capital there.’’1 The enormous
influx of wealth overflowed the capacities of the old feudal relations of
production. English capitalists sprang up to embody the new regime of
command that could exploit this new wealth.
It would be a mistake, however, to take the English experience of
becoming-proletarian and becoming-capitalist as representative of all the
others. Over the last three hundred years, as capitalist relations of production
and reproduction have spread across the world, although primitive accumulation has always involved separating the producer from the means of production
and thereby creating classes of proletarians and capitalists, each process of
social transformation has nonetheless been unique. In each case the social
and productive relations that preexisted were different, the processes of the
transition were different, and even the form of the resulting capitalist relations
of production and especially those of reproduction were different in line with
specific cultural and historical differences.
Despite these important differences, it is still useful to group the
modern processes of primitive accumulation under two general models that
highlight the relationship between wealth and command, and between
inside and outside.
In all cases, the primitive accumulation of capital requires a
new combination of wealth and command. What is distinctive about the
first model, which Marx described for England and which applies generally
to Europe as a whole, is that the new wealth for the primitive accumulation
of capital comes from the outside (from the colonial territories) and the
command arises internally (through the evolution of English and European
258
P A S S A G E S O F P R O D U C T I O N
relations of production). According to the second model, which characterizes
most of the modern processes of primitive accumulation outside Europe, the
terms are reversed, such that the new wealth arises from within and command
comes from the outside (usually European capital). This inversion of wealth/
command and inside/outside in the two models leads to a whole series of
differences in the economic, political, and social formations of capital across
the world. Many of these differences deriving from the two models were
described adequately by theorists of underdevelopment in terms of central
and peripheral capitalist formations.2
As we pass from modernity to postmodernity, the processes of primitive
accumulation do indeed continue. Primitive accumulation is not a process
that happens once and then is done with; rather, capitalist relations of
production and social classes have to be reproduced continually. What has
changed is the model or mode of primitive accumulation. First of all, the
play between inside and outside that distinguishes the two modern models
has progressively declined. More important, the nature of the labor and
wealth accumulated is changing. In postmodernity the social wealth accumulated is increasingly immaterial; it involves social relations, communication
systems, information, and affective networks. Correspondingly, social labor
is increasingly more immaterial; it simultaneously produces and reproduces
directly all aspects of social life. As the proletariat is becoming the universal
figure of labor, the object of proletarian labor is becoming equally universal.
Social labor produces life itself.
We should emphasize the central role that informational accumulation
plays in the processes of postmodern primitive accumulation and the ever
greater socialization of production. As the new informational economy
emerges, a certain accumulation of information is necessary before capitalist
production can take place. Information carries through its networks both the
wealth and the command of production, disrupting previous conceptions of
inside and outside, but also reducing the temporal progression that had
previously defined primitive accumulation. In other words, informational
accumulation (like the primitive accumulation Marx analyzed) destroys or
at least destructures the previously existing productive processes, but (differently than Marx’s primitive accumulation) it immediately integrates those
productive processes in its own networks and generates across the different
D I S C I P L I N A R Y G O V E R N A B I L I T Y
259
realms of production the highest levels of productivity. The temporal sequence
of development is thus reduced to immediacy as the entire society tends to
be integrated in some way into the networks of informational production.
Information networks tend toward something like
a simultaneity ofsocial production.
The revolution of informational accumulation therefore requires
an enormous leap forward in the greater socialization of production. This
increased socialization, along with the reduction of social space and temporality, is a process that no doubt benefits capital with increased productivity,
but is one also that points beyond the era of capital toward a new social
mode of production.
3.3
R E S I S T A N C E , C R I S I S , T R A N S F O R M A T I O N
The continuity ofstruggle is easy: the workers need only them-
selves and the boss in front of them. But the continuity of organiza-
tion is a rare and complex thing: as soon as it is institutionalized it
quickly becomes used by capitalism, or by the workers’ movement
in the service ofcapitalism.
Mario Tronti
The New Left sprang . . . from Elvis’s gyrating pelvis.
Jerry Rubin
Earlier we posed the Vietnam War as a deviation from
the U.S. constitutional project and its tendency toward Empire.
The war was also, however, an expression of the desire for freedom
ofthe Vietnamese, an expression ofpeasant and proletarian subjec-
tivity—a fundamental example of resistance against both the final
forms of imperialism and the international disciplinary regime. The
Vietnam War represents a real turning point in the history ofcon-
temporary capitalism insofar as the Vietnamese resistance is con-
ceived as the symbolic center ofa whole series ofstruggles around
the world that had up until that point remained separate and distant
from one another. The peasantry who were being subsumed under
multinational capital, the (post)colonial proletariat, the industrial
working class in the dominant capitalist countries, and the new
strata ofintellectual proletariat everywhere all tended toward a
common site ofexploitation in the factory-society ofthe globalized
R E S I S T A N C E , C R I S I S , T R A N S F O R M A T I O N
261
disciplinary regime. The various struggles converged against one
common enemy:
the international disciplinary order.
An objective unity was established, sometimes with the consciousness ofthose in struggle and sometimes without. The long cycle ofstruggles against the
disciplinary regimes had reached maturity and forced capital to
modify its own structures and undergo a paradigm shift.
Two, Three, Many Vietnams
In the late 1960s the international system ofcapitalist production
was in crisis.1 Capitalist crisis, as Marx tells us, is a situation that
requires capital to undergo a general devaluation and a profound
rearrangement ofthe relations ofproduction as a result ofthe
downward pressure that the proletariat puts on the rate ofprofit.
In other words, capitalist crisis is not simply a function of capital’s
own dynamics but is caused directly by proletarian conflict.2 This
Marxian notion ofcrisis helps bring to light the most important
features ofthe crisis ofthe late 1960s. The fall ofthe rate ofprofit
and the disruption ofrelations ofcommand in this period are best
understood when seen as a
result
ofthe confluence and accumulation ofproletarian and anticapitalist attacks against the international capitalist system.
In the dominant capitalist countries, this period witnessed a
worker attack ofthe highest intensity directed primarily against the
disciplinary regimes ofcapitalist labor. The attack was expressed,
first ofall, as a general refusal ofwork and specifically as a refusal
offactory work. It was aimed against productivity and against any
model ofdevelopment based on increasing the productivity of
factory labor. The refusal of the disciplinary regime and the affirma-
tion ofthe sphere ofnon-work became the defining features ofa
new set ofcollective practices and a new form oflife.3 Second, the
attack served to subvert the capitalist divisions ofthe labor market.
The three primary characteristics ofthe labor market—the separa-
tion ofsocial groups (by class strata, race, ethnicity, or sex), the
fluidity ofthe labor market (social mobility, tertiarization, new
relations between directly and indirectly productive labor, and so
262
P A S S A G E S O F P R O D U C T I O N
forth), and the hierarchies ofthe market ofabstract labor—were
all threatened by the rising rigidity and commonality ofworker
demands. The increasing socialization ofcapital led also toward the
social unification ofthe proletariat. This increasingly unified voice
posed the general demand for a guaranteed social wage and a very
high level ofwelfare.4 Third, and finally, the worker attack was