Authors: Professor Michael Hardt,Antonio Negri
Tags: #Philosophy, #Political, #Political Science, #General, #American Government
value, conflicts with the internalization ofthe noncapitalist environ-
ment, which satisfies the need to capitalize that realized surplus
value. Historically these two processes have often taken place in
sequence. A territory and population are first made accessible as an
outside for exchange and realization, and then subsequently brought
into the realm ofcapitalist production proper. The important point,
however, is that once a segment ofthe environment has been
‘‘civilized,’’ once it has been organically incorporated into the newly
expanded boundaries ofthe domain ofcapitalist production, it can
no longer be the outside necessary to realize capital’s surplus value.
In this sense, capitalization poses a barrier to realization and vice
versa; or better, internalization contradicts the reliance on the out-
side. Capital’s thirst must be quenched with new blood, and it must
continually seek new frontiers.
It is logical to assume that there would come a time when
these two moments ofthe cycle ofaccumulation, realization and
capitalization, come into direct conflict and undermine each other.
In the nineteenth century, the field for capitalist expansion (in
material resources, labor power, and markets) seemed to stretch
indefinitely, both in Europe and elsewhere. In Marx’s time, capitalist
production accounted for very little of global production. Only a
few countries had substantial capitalist production (England, France,
228
P A S S A G E S O F P R O D U C T I O N
and Germany), and even these countries still had large segments of
noncapitalist production—peasant-based agriculture, artisanal pro-
duction, and so forth. Luxemburg argues, however, that since the
earth is finite, the logical conflict will eventually become a real
contradiction: ‘‘The more violently, ruthlessly and thoroughly im-
perialism brings about the decline ofnon-capitalist civilisations, the
more rapidly it cuts the ground from under the feet of capitalist
accumulation. Though imperialism is the historical method for
prolonging the career ofcapitalism, it is also the sure means of
bringing it to a swift conclusion.’’16 This contradictory tension is
present throughout the development ofcapital, but it is revealed
in full view only at the limit, at the point of crisis—when capital
is faced with the finitude of humanity and the earth. Here the great
imperialist Cecil Rhodes appears as the paradigmatic capitalist. The
spaces ofthe globe are closing up and capital’s imperialist expansion
is confronting its limits. Rhodes, ever the adventurer, gazes wistfully
and yearningly at the stars above, frustrated by the cruel temptation
of those new frontiers, so close and yet so far.
Even though their critiques ofimperialism and capitalist expan-
sion are often presented in strictly quantitative, economic terms,
the stakes for Marxist theorists are primarily
political.
This does not mean that the economic calculations (and the critiques ofthem)
should not be taken seriously; it means, rather, that the economic
relationships must be considered as they are really articulated in the
historical and social context, as part ofpolitical relations ofrule and
domination.17 The most important political stake for these authors
in the question ofeconomic expansion is to demonstrate the ineluc-
table relationship between capitalism and imperialism. Ifcapitalism
and imperialism are essentially related, the logic goes, then any
struggle against imperialism (and the wars, misery, impoverishment,
and enslavement that follow from it) must also be a direct struggle
against capitalism. Any political strategy aimed at reforming the
contemporary configuration ofcapitalism to make it nonimperialist
is vain and naive because the core ofcapitalist reproduction and
accumulation necessarily implies imperialist expansion. Capital can-
T H E L I M I T S O F I M P E R I A L I S M
229
not behave otherwise—this is its nature. The evils ofimperialism
cannot be confronted except by destroying capitalism itself.
Equalization and Subsumption
Lenin’s book on imperialism is cast primarily as a synthesis ofthe
analyses ofother authors to make them accessible to a wide public.18
Lenin’s text, however, also makes its own original contributions,
the most important ofwhich is to pose the critique ofimperialism
from the subjective standpoint and thus link it to the Marxist notion
ofthe revolutionary potential ofcrises. He gave us a toolbox, a set
ofmachines for the production ofanti-imperialist subjectivity.
Lenin often presents his arguments by way of polemic. His
analysis ofimperialism is articulated primarily by challenging the
theses ofRudolfHilferding and Karl Kautsky. In order to develop
his critiques, however, Lenin considered carefully, and at times
assumed as his own, the theoretical assumptions ofboth these au-
thors. Most important, Lenin adopted Hilferding’s fundamental
thesis that as capital expands through the imperialist construction
ofthe world market, there emerge ever greater obstacles to the
Ausgleichung
(the equalization) ofrates ofprofit among various
branches and sectors ofproduction. Peaceful capitalist development,
however, depends on at least a tendency toward equalized economic
conditions: equal prices for equal commodities, equal profit for
equal capital, equal wages and equal exploitation for equal work,
and so forth. Hilferding recognized that imperialism—which struc-
tures the nations and territories ofcapitalist development in an ever
more rigid way and assigns authority to national monopolies—
impedes the formation ofan equalized rate ofprofit and thus under-
mines the possibility ofa successful capitalist mediation ofinterna-
tional development.19 In effect, the domination and division of the
world market by monopolies had made the process ofequalization
virtually impossible. Only ifthe national central banks were to
intervene, or better, ifa unified international bank were to inter-
vene, could this contradiction, which portends both trade wars and
fighting wars, be equalized and placated. In short, Lenin adopted
230
P A S S A G E S O F P R O D U C T I O N
Hilferding’s hypothesis that capital had entered a new phase of
international development defined by monopoly and that this led
to both an increase ofcontradictions and a crisis ofequalization.
He did not accept, however, that the utopia ofa unified international
bank could be taken seriously and that a still capitalist
Aufhebung
(subsumption) ofthe crisis could ever come about.
Lenin regarded the position ofKautsky, who also took Hilferd-
ing’s work as his point ofdeparture, as even more utopian and
damaging. Kautsky proposed, in effect, that capitalism could achieve
a real political and economic unification ofthe world market. The
violent conflicts of imperialism could be followed by a new peaceful
phase ofcapitalism, an ‘‘ultra-imperialist’’ phase. The magnates of
capital could unite in a single world trust, substituting an internation-
ally united finance capital for the competition and struggle between
nationally based finance capitals. We can thus imagine a phase
in the future, he claimed, in which capital achieves a peaceful
subsumption and resolution in which not a unified bank but market
forces and monopolies more or less regulated by states could succeed
somehow in determining the global equalization ofthe rate of
profit.20 Lenin agreed with Kautsky’s basic thesis that there is a
trend in capitalist development toward the international cooperation
ofthe various national finance capitals and possibly toward the
construction ofa single world trust. What he objected to so strongly
was the fact that Kautsky used this vision of a peaceful future to
negate the dynamics ofthe present reality; Lenin thus denounced
his ‘‘profoundly reactionary desire to blunt the contradictions’’ of
the present situation.21 Rather than waiting for some peaceful ultra-
imperialism to arrive in the future, revolutionaries should act now on
the contradictions posed by capital’s present imperialist organization.
Thus, while generally adopting these authors’ analytical propo-
sitions, Lenin rejected their political positions. Although he funda-
mentally agreed with Hilferding’s analysis of the tendency toward
a world market dominated by monopolies, he denied that such a
system was already in effect in such a way that it could mediate
and equalize the rate ofprofit. He denied this not so much theoreti-
T H E L I M I T S O F I M P E R I A L I S M
231
cally as politically. Lenin maintained that capitalist development in
the monopoly phase would be plagued by a series ofcontradictions
and that communists had to act on them. It was the responsibility
ofthe workers’ movement to oppose every capitalist attempt at
organizing an effective equalization of imperialist rates of profit,
and it was the task ofthe revolutionary party to intervene in and
deepen the objective contradictions ofdevelopment. What had to
be avoided most was the realization ofthe tendency toward ‘‘ultra-
imperialism,’’ which would monstrously increase the power ofcapi-
tal and take away for a long period to come the possibility of
struggles on the most contradictory and thus weakest links in the
chain ofdomination. Lenin writes, either as hope or as prediction,
‘‘This development proceeds in such circumstances, at such a pace,
through such contradictions, conflicts and upheavals—not only
economic but political, national, etc.—that inevitably imperialism
will burst and capitalism will be transformed into its opposite
long
before
one world trust materialises, before the ‘ultra-imperialist,’
world-wide amalgamation ofnational finance capitals takes place.’’22
Lenin’s logical de´marche here between analytical propositions
and political positions was certainly tortuous. Nevertheless, his rea-
soning was very effective from the subjective point of view. As Ilya
Babel said, Lenin’s thought ran along ‘‘the mysterious curve ofthe
straight line’’ that carried the analysis ofthe reality ofthe working
class to the necessity ofits political organization. Lenin recognized
the untimely element ofthe definition ofimperialism and grasped
in the subjective practices ofthe working class not only the potential
obstacles to the linear solution ofthe crises ofcapitalist realization
(which Luxemburg emphasized too), but also the existing and con-
crete possibility that these practices—struggles, insurrections, and
revolutions—could destroy imperialism itself.23 In this sense Lenin
took the critique ofimperialism from theory to practice.
From Imperialism to Empire
One ofthe most remarkable aspects ofLenin’s analysis is his critique
ofimperialism as a political concept. Lenin brought together the
232
P A S S A G E S O F P R O D U C T I O N
problematic ofmodern sovereignty and that ofcapitalist develop-
ment under the lens ofone unified critique, and by weaving together
the different lines of critique, he was able to glimpse beyond moder-
nity. In other words, through his political re-elaboration ofthe
concept ofimperialism, Lenin, more than any other Marxist, was
able to anticipate the passage to a new phase ofcapital beyond
imperialism and identify the place (or really the non-place) of emerg-
ing imperial sovereignty.
When Lenin studied imperialism, he focused his attention not
only on the work ofthe various recent Marxist authors but also
further back to the work of John Hobson and his bourgeois populist
version ofthe critique ofimperialism.24 Lenin learned a great deal
from Hobson—which, incidentally, he could have learned equally
well from the German, French, or Italian populist theorists of impe-
rialism. In particular, he learned that the modern European nation-
states use imperialism to transfer outside their own borders the
political contradictions that arise within each single country. The
nation-state asks imperialism to resolve or really displace class strug-
gle and its destabilizing effects. Cecil Rhodes expressed the essence
ofthis function ofimperialism most clearly: ‘‘My cherished idea is
a solution for the social problem, i.e., in order to save the 40,000,000
inhabitants ofthe United Kingdom from a bloody civil war, we
colonial statesmen must acquire new lands to settle the surplus
population, to provide new markets for the goods produced by
them in the factories and mines. The Empire, as I have always said,
is a bread and butter question. Ifyou want to avoid civil war, you
must become imperialists.’’25 Through imperialism, the modern
state exports class struggle and civil war in order to preserve order
and sovereignty at home.
Lenin saw imperialism as a structural stage in the evolution
ofthe modern state. He imagined a necessary and linear historical
progression from the first forms of the modern European state to